Anna
van Zoest from the Institute of Public Policy and Research states how it
appears that “the dominant argument for companies to move business processes
offshore are lower production costs caused mainly by low wages in countries
outside of Europe, the US and Japan. An average ICT worker in India earns one
seventh of the amount earned by his British counterpart, and a call centre
agent even less. According to the McKinsey Global Institute, companies can save
over 45% on production costs when moving business segments offshore, (McKinsey,
2003).”
This
is supported by Katerina Rudiger of the Work Foundation, who highlights in a
2007 article that, “to this date, the phenomenon of labour arbitrage, the huge
wage gap between industrialised and developing countries, has played an
important role in offshore outsourcing. This is why Alan Blinder has called the
phenomenon of offshore outsourcing the migration of jobs, but not the people
who perform them, from rich countries to poor ones.”
Actual
data seems to be very limited, as if the subject of outsourcing offshore is
taboo and the less said the better. The problem with this is, in a depressed
economy with high unemployment and areas of real poverty, the lack of data just
fuels the flames of discontent, concern, misunderstanding and fear around
‘local’ jobs being sent overseas.
An
article by Alex Lach highlights how in the US “data from the U.S. Department of
Commerce showed that U.S. multinational corporations, the big brand-name
companies that employ a fifth of all American workers cut their work forces in
the U.S. by 2.9 million during the 2000s while increasing employment overseas
by 2.4 million.”
Where,
“according to a report on outsourcing by Working America, manufacturing
employment collapsed from a high of 19.5 million workers in June 1979 to 11.5
workers in December 2009, a drop of 8 million workers over 30 years. Between
August 2000 and February 2004, manufacturing jobs were lost for a stunning 43
consecutive months - the longest such stretch since the Great Depression.
Manufacturing plants have also declined sharply in the last decade, shrinking
by more than 51,000 plants, or 12.5 percent, between 1998 and 2008. These stable,
middle-class jobs have been the driving force of the U.S. economy for decades
and theses losses have done considerable damage to communities across the
country”.
According
to research from the Hackett Group, the cost gap between the United States and
China has shrunk by nearly 50 percent over the past eight years, and is
expected to stand at just 16 percent this year. Labour costs in China and
elsewhere are rising, and coupled with rising fuel prices raising shipping
costs, the economic argument for sending jobs overseas may be becoming less
persuasive. Despite these increasing costs, the Duke survey found that only 4
percent of large companies had any future plans for relocating jobs back to the
United States. The Duke survey does not identify the reasons for this
reluctance to bring these jobs back to the US, but Alex Lach suggests that “a
key factor could be the U.S. tax code”, which, as Seth Hanlon explains,
“rewards companies for making investments abroad and leads to them shifting
offices, factories, and jobs abroad even if similar investments in the United
States would be more profitable absent of tax considerations.”
Although
a complex topic, the basic equation for disaster is simple – if you create
local unemployment because you outsource part of your business set-up overseas,
then although you may have reduced you own costs, you have in the process
reduced the disposable income available in your own country.
Once
the cycle starts, it can become a never ending spiral of disaster, where with
less domestic income available to spend, other organisations across the
industry spectrum automatically presume the only way forward is to cut their
prices to attract the diminished spending power. This will inevitably lead them
to look at ways to reduce costs in order to keep their shareholders happy, and
in the process they are likely to look offshore - where in a ‘heartbeat’ you’ve
the potential to create more unemployment and even less disposable income at
home – and so the cycle continues.
There
are strong views on both sides, from the economic view of a free market economy
and optimising shareholder value to the social view, concerned with the impact
of unemployment on society. But the two shouldn’t be considered mutually
exclusive, where government and business should focus on socio-economic
solutions for their home country first, and then they are in a stronger
position to help developing nations. But there is a real danger if you help
develop other countries at the expense of your own citizens that sometime in
the not too distant future your whole country could lose.
References:
Lach,
A. (2012). 5 Facts About Overseas Outsourcing. Centre for American Progress.
[On-line:
http://www.americanprogress.org/issues/labor/news/2012/07/09/11898/5-facts-about-overseas-outsourcing/]
Rudiger,
K. (2007). Offshoring, a threat for the UK’s knowledge jobs? Globalisation and
the extent and impact of offshore outsourcing. The Work Foundation. [On-line: http://www.theworkfoundation.com]
Van
Zoest, A. (2004). Offshoring Practices in the UK – Where Are the Limits.
Institute for Public Policy and Research. [On-line: http://www.ippr.org/uploadedFiles/projects/]
No comments:
Post a Comment